class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide # OLG Model: Dynamics ## Macroeconomics (2017Q2) ### Kenji Sato ### 2017-07-27 --- $$\let\oldhat\hat \renewcommand{\hat}[1]{\oldhat{\hspace{0pt} #1}}$$ <div style="margin-top: -2.3em"></div> ## Dynamics of the OLG model The dynamics of the capital per unit of effective labor `\(\hat k_t\)` obeys `$$\begin{aligned} \hat{k}_{t+1} = \frac{s\left(f'(\hat{k}_{t+1})\right) \left[f(\hat{k}_{t})-\hat{k}_{t}f'(\hat{k}_{t})\right]} {(1+g)(1+n)}, \end{aligned}$$` This is an implicit system (the left- and right-hand sides both contain `\(\hat{k}_{t+1}\)`). `\(k_{t+1}\)` may not be a function of `\(k_{t}\)`, in which case there is multiple possibilities for the time path. --- ## Cobb-Douglas Production and Log Utility To obtain a clear result, we assume that `$$\begin{aligned} f(k)=k^{\alpha},\quad0<\alpha<1 \end{aligned}$$` and the log instantaneous utility function: i.e., `\(\theta=1\)`. The dynamics is characterized by `$$\begin{aligned} \hat{k}_{t+1}=\frac{(1-\alpha)}{(1+g)(1+n)(2+\rho)}\hat{k}_{t}^{\alpha} \end{aligned}$$` This is analogous to the Solow model. --- ## Cobb-Douglas Production and Log Utility (Stability) It can be shown that for any `\(\hat k_0 > 0\)` `$$\begin{aligned} \hat k_t \to \hat{k}^{*}=\left[\frac{1-\alpha}{(1+n)(1+g)(2+\rho)}\right]^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \end{aligned}$$` as `\(t \to \infty\)`. The prediction of the Solow model is preserved. For instance, per-capita capital `$$\begin{aligned} k_t = A_t \hat k_t \end{aligned}$$` grows at the rate of `\(g\)` in the long run. --- ## Dynamic Inefficiency OLG models may have **dynamic inefficiency** in that at least one generation can increase utility without no generation else reducing utility. Let's continue to assume that the production function is C-D and utility is log. The steady state for capital per unit of effective labor satisfies `$$\begin{aligned} \hat{k}^{*}=\left[\frac{1-\alpha}{(1+n)(1+g)(2+\rho)}\right]^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}} \end{aligned}$$` --- ## Dynamic Inefficiency (cont'd) `$$\begin{aligned} f'\left(\hat{k}^{*}\right) &= \alpha\left(\left[ \frac{1-\alpha}{(1+n)(1+g)(2+\rho)} \right]^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha}}\right)^{\alpha-1}\\ &= \frac{\alpha(1+n)(1+g)(2+\rho)}{1-\alpha}. \end{aligned}$$` The golden rule capital stock `\(\hat k_G\)` satisfies (under `\(\delta = 0\)`): `$$\begin{aligned} f'(\hat{k}_{G}) = n + g \end{aligned}$$` --- ## Dynamic Inefficiency (cont'd) The golden rule capital stock `\(\hat k_G\)` satisfies (under `\(\delta = 0\)`): `$$\begin{aligned} f'(\hat{k}_{G}) = n + g \end{aligned}$$` Thus, `$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\alpha(1+n)(1+g)(2+\rho)}{1-\alpha} < n + g \Longleftrightarrow \hat{k}^* > \hat k_G \end{aligned}$$` If `\(\alpha\)` is sufficiently small, the above inequalities hold and it gives rise to dynamic inefficiency. In OLG models, the fact that there is no coordination between generations may result in too much saving. --- ## Reallocation Let's suppose `\(\hat{k}^* > \hat k_G\)` and that the economy is on the BGP. If some social planner forces - young people in period `\(t_{0}\)` to consume more and save less by some amount `\(\Delta > 0\)` by which the economy moves to `\(\hat{k}_{G}\)`, - people in subsequent periods consume the golden rule level --- ## Reallocation (cont'd) Consumption per effective worker in period `\(t_{0}\)` satisfies: `$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{k}^{*})+(\hat{k}^{*}-\hat{k}_{G})-(g+n)\hat{k}_{G} &> f(\hat{k}_{G})-(g+n) \hat{k}_{G}\\ &> f(\hat{k}^{*})-(g+n)\hat{k}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$` All generations potentially become better off by this reallocation. The original saving rate was too high. --- ## Reallocation (cont'd) #### consumption in period `\(t_0\)` `$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{k}^{*})+(\hat{k}^{*}-\hat{k}_{G})-(g+n)\hat{k}_{G} \end{aligned}$$` #### consumption in period `\(t > t_0\)` `$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{k}_{G})-(g+n) \hat{k}_{G} \end{aligned}$$` #### consumption without the reallocation `$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{k}^{*})-(g+n)\hat{k}^{*} \end{aligned}$$` --- ## Dynamic efficiency of the Ramsey model In the Ramsey model, it always holds that `$$\begin{aligned} \hat k^* < \hat k_G \end{aligned}$$` So, there is no dynamic inefficiency in the Ramsey model. --- ## Multiple equilibrium Let's go back to the implicit equation. By rearranging terms, we have `$$\begin{aligned} f(\hat{k}_{t})-\hat{k}_{t}f'(\hat{k}_{t}) = \frac{(1+g)(1+n)\hat k_{t+1}}{s\left( f'(\hat k_{t+1}) \right)} \end{aligned}$$` Define `\(w(k) = f(k) - kf'(k)\)`. Since - `\(w(k)\)` is increasing in `\(k\)` - `\(w(0) = 0\)`, and - the right-hand side is positive --- ## Inverse dynamics Given `\(\hat k_{t+1}\)`, we can solve for a unique `\(\hat k_t\)` that satisfies the above equation. We have the **inverse dynamics** (`\(\hat k_{t+1} \mapsto \hat k_t\)`) This dynamic system possesses many interesting properties. To see examples, we use CES production function: $$f(k) = A (\alpha k^\gamma + 1-\alpha)^{1 / \gamma} $$ --- class: small ## Code ```r OLG = function(theta, rho, g, n, alpha, gamma, A) { f = function(k) A * (alpha * k ^ gamma + 1 - alpha) ^ (1 / gamma) df = function(k) A * alpha * (alpha + (1 - alpha) * k ^ (-gamma)) ^ ((1 - gamma) / gamma) w = function(k) f(k) - k * df(k) w_inv = function(y) { sol = nleqslv::nleqslv(100, function(x) w(x) - y) if (sol$termcd == 1) return(sol$x) else return(NA) } s = function(r){ sigma = (1 - theta) / theta return((1 + r) ^ sigma) / ((1 + rho) ^ (1 / theta) + (1 + r) ^ sigma) } w2 = function(k) (1 + g) * (1 + n) * k / s(df(k)) return(list(f=f, df=df, w=w, w_inv=w_inv, w2=w2)) } ``` --- ## Typical Case <img src="day13_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-2-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- ## Multiple Equilibrium (Poverty Trap) <img src="day13_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- ## Multiple Steady States (Self-fulfilling prophecy) <img src="day13_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.png" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- ## Multiple Steady States (Self-fulfilling prophecy) Comments on the previous figure. A path that starts from somewhere very close to the middle steady state (which is unstable) is not entirely determined by the initial condition. (Indeterminacy) Because the agents have three possible `\(\hat k_{t+1}\)`. The path they choose is affected by non-fundamental factors (called **sunspots**). If they _believe_ the economy experiences boom, they choose the higer `\(\hat k_{t+1}\)` and the economy converges to the higher steady state. Their belief has the power to make it true. --- class: center, middle # Government --- ## Government in the Diamond model Let's introduce a government in the Diamond OLG model. We consider a government that finances its expense with - lump-sum tax We only modify the household behavior. --- ## Household Young individuals, who are born without financial wealth, supply unit labor and earn wage. They divide their income between consumption, saving, **and tax**. When they become old, they simply consume what you can buy with the saving and the interest they will have earned. --- ## Notation - Let `\(c_{t}^{Y}\)` be the consumption of the representative consumer in generation `\(t\)` when they are young, (per capita consumption) - `\(G_t\)` be the lump-sum tax levied on the young (per-capita basis, _not_ per-effective labor basis) - `\(c_{t+1}^{O}\)` be the consumption of the representative consumer in generation `\(t\)` when they are old. --- ## Household optimization `$$\begin{aligned} &\max_{c_{t}^{Y},c_{t+1}^{O},s_{t}} \frac{\left(c_{t}^{Y}\right)^{1-\theta}}{1-\theta} + \frac{1}{1+\rho}\frac{\left(c_{t+1}^{O}\right)^{1-\theta}}{1-\theta}\\ &\text{subject to }\\ &\qquad c_{t}^{Y}+s_{t}+G_t=w_{t},\\ &\qquad c_{t+1}^{O}=(1+r_{t+1})s_{t}. \end{aligned}$$` --- ## Solution Assume `$$\theta = 1, \quad \text{and} \quad F(K, AL) = K^\alpha (AL)^{1-\alpha}$$` According to the textbook, the equilibrium dynamics is given by `$$\hat{k}_{t+1}=\frac{1}{(1+g)(1+n)(2+\rho)} \left[(1-\alpha) \hat{k}_{t}^{\alpha} - \hat G_t\right],$$` where `\(\hat G_t = G_t / A_t\)`. (See Problem Set O) --- ## Implication Unlike the Ramsey model, anticipation about future stream of the government purchases **does not** affect the individual behavior. This is because an individual's consumption in their old age is solely determined by the tax in the period when they are young.